CONSUMER SURPLUS
Defining Consumer Surplus
Consumer
surplus is a measure of the welfare
that people gain from the consumption of goods and services, or a measure of
the benefits they derive from the exchange of goods.
Consumer
surplus is the difference between the total amount that consumers are willing and able to pay for
a good or service (indicated by the demand curve) and the total amount that
they actually do pay (i.e. the market price for the product). The level of
consumer surplus is shown by the area under the demand curve and above the
ruling market price as illustrated in the diagram below:

Consumer surplus and price elasticity of demand
When
the demand for a good or service is perfectly elastic, consumer surplus is zero
because the price that people pay matches precisely the price they are willing
to pay. This is most likely to happen in highly competitive markets where each
individual firm is assumed to be a ‘price
taker’ in their chosen market and must sell as much as it can
at the ruling market price.
In
contrast, when demand is perfectly inelastic, consumer surplus is infinite.
Demand is totally invariant to a price change. Whatever the price, the quantity
demanded remains the same (remember out gasoline example earlier in the
course).
The
majority of demand curves are downward sloping. When demand is inelastic, there
is a greater potential consumer surplus because there are some buyers willing
to pay a high price to continue consuming the product. This is shown in the
diagram below:

Changes in demand and consumer surplus

In
the diagram on the right we see the effects of a cost reducing innovation which
causes an outward shift of market supply, a lower price and an increase in the
quantity traded in the market. As a result, there is an increase in consumer
welfare shown by a rise in consumer surplus.
Consumer surplus can be used frequently when analysing the impact of government intervention in any market – for example the effects of indirect taxation on cigarettes consumers or the introducing of road pricing schemes such as the London congestion charge.
Consumer surplus can be used frequently when analysing the impact of government intervention in any market – for example the effects of indirect taxation on cigarettes consumers or the introducing of road pricing schemes such as the London congestion charge.
Applications of Consumer Surplus
Consider
the entry of Internet retailers such as Last Minute and Amazon into the markets
for travel and books respectively. What
impact has their entry into the market had on consumer surplus? Have you
benefited from you perceive to be lower prices and better deals as a result of
using e-commerce sites offering large discounts compared to high street
retailers?
Price discrimination and consumer surplus
Producers
often take advantage of consumer surplus when setting prices. If a business can
identify groups of consumers within their market who are willing and able to
pay different prices for the same products, then sellers may engage in price discrimination
– the aim of which is to extract from the purchaser, the price they are willing
to pay, thereby turning consumer surplus into extra revenue. Ever noticed the
price changes at your local fitness gym?
Airlines
are expert at practising this form of yield
management, extracting from consumers the price they are
willing and able to pay for flying to different destinations are various times
of the day, and exploiting variations
in elasticity of demand for different types of passenger
service. You will always get a better deal / price with airlines such as
WestJet and Air Canada
if you are prepared to book weeks or months in advance. The airlines are
prepared to sell tickets more cheaply then because they get the benefit of
cash-flow together with the guarantee of a seat being filled. The nearer the
time to take-off, the higher the price. If a businessman is desperate to fly
from Vancouver to Toronto in 24 hours time, his or her demand
is said to be price inelastic and the corresponding price for the ticket will
be much higher. Would you expect profitability per seat sold to vary greatly for
airlines, why?
One
of the main arguments against firms with monopoly
power is that they exploit their monopoly position by raising
prices in markets where demand is inelastic, extracting consumer surplus from
buyers and increasing profit margins at the same time. Is this a valid
argument?
Consumer and Producer
Surplus
ARSC 1432
Microeconomics Co-Seminar
SPRING 2009
Consumer
Surplus
= CS = the difference between what consumers are willing to pay and what
they actually pay for a good or service.
Producer
Surplus =
PS = the difference between what producers are willing to accept for
their produce and what they actually receive for a good or service.
Social
Surplus =
SS = CS + PS

To calculate CS or PS, use the formula
for area of a triangle:
(½)(base)(height)
Example 1:

Example 2:
Ps = 40 + 4Qs Supply Equation
Pd = 100 – 2Qd Demand Equation
To find Equilibrium Ps*=Pd*
at equilibrium they are equal
so
40+4Qs=100-2Qd or 40+4Q=100-2Q
since Qs=Qd also
6Q=60
Q*=60/6=10 Equilibrium quantity
Now to find the price Ps*=40+ 4(10) = 80 or
Pd*=100-2(10) = 80
So to graph we say how much is the price when the
quantity demanded (or supplied) is zero in both equations Ps = 40 + 4(0)=
40 Pd = 100 – 2(0) = 100. These are the
intercepts at the Y axis.
To calculate the intercept at the X
axis we say how much is the quantity demanded when the price is zero, so 0 =
100 -2Qd 2Qd=100 Qd=100/2=50
there is no need to calculate the X intercept for the supply equation.

Since Consumer Surplus and Producer
Surplus are represented by triangles, to calculate their value you can utilize
the formula for the area of a triangle =
.

So Consumer Surplus is equal to ((100-80) x 10)/2 = (20 x 10)/2= 100
and Producer Surplus is equal to ((80-40) x 10)/2 = (40 x 10)/2= 200
So Total Welfare equals Consumer
Surplus + Producer Surplus = 100 + 200 = 300
Definition of 'Economic Growth'
An increase in the capacity of an
economy to produce goods and services, compared from one period of time
to another. Economic growth can be measured in nominal terms, which include
inflation, or in real terms, which are adjusted for inflation. For comparing
one country's economic growth to another, GDP or GNP per capita should be
used as these take into account population differences between countries.
|
|
![]() |
Investopedia explains 'Economic Growth'
Economic growth is usually
associated with technological changes. An example is the large growth in the U.S. economy during the introduction of the
Internet and the technology that it brought to U.S. industry as a whole. The
growth of an economy is thought of not only as an increase in productive
capacity but also as an improvement in the quality of life to the people of
that economy.
|
Eco B
- 1
ECONOMICS
We may define economic activity as any
action that helps in the satisfaction of human wants. It is this activity which
forms the subject-matter of the study of economics.
Economics
originally developed as a science of statecraft.
Definitions of economics:
1. Wealth definition - by
Adam Smith approach/school/thought
2. Welfare definition - by Alfred Marshall
3. Scarcity definition – by Lionel Robbins
4. Growth definition – by Paul
A. Samuelson
1 Wealth
definition – Wealth has always assumedتظاهر کردن a significant role to control and regulate the economic
activity. But with the development of trade, industry and commerce, the role of
wealth has become more dominantغالب. Economists in the 18th and the early 19th
centuries had defined economics as that part of knowledge which relates to
wealth.
Adam Smith defined economics as “a
science which studies the nature and causes of the wealth of nations”.
2 Welfareآسایش definition – Alfred
Marshall defined economics as:
“Political economy or Economics is a
study of mankind in the ordinary business of life; it examines that part of
individual and social action which is most closely connected with the
attainment حصولand with the
use of the material requisites
احتیاج of well-being. Thus it
is, on the one side, a study of wealth; and on the other, and more important
side, a part of the study of man”.
Marshall was the first
to realize the significance of human welfare. He believed that wealth is not an
end in itself, it is a means to an end, the ultimate نهاییend being human welfare.
3. Scarcity کمیابی Definition – Lionel Robbins
defined economics as ;
“Economics
is the science which studies human behavior as a relationship between ends and
scarce means which have alternative uses.”
The definition of Robbins bring home
the following fundamental conditions:
·
Economics
is a science – a positive science – because it studies how human beings adjust
their multiple wants to scarce means.
·
Economics
studies human behavior.
·
Ends
– Ends refer to the human wants which are unlimited.
·
Scarce
means – Human wants are unlimited while the means (material resources) to
satisfy them are limited.
4. Growth Definition - Professor
Paul A. Samuelson has propounded
اریرایه کردن the growth-centered definition of economics;
“Economics is the study of how man and
society choose, with or without the use of money, to employ scarce productive
resources which could have alternative uses, to produce various commodities وسیله
مناسب over time and distribute them for consumption مصرفnow and in future among various
people and groups of society.’
MICRO
ECONOMICS
Micro and macro have come to be known
as two important approaches to the economic analysis. Micro has been taken from
the Greek word ‘Mikros’ which means small.
Professor Ragner Frisch coined this term for the first time in 1933, and
since then it has become an important approach of economic analysis.
“Micro economics is the study of
particular firm, particular household, individual price, wage, income, industry
and particular commodity”. (K. E. Boulding)
Scope هدف
of Micro Economics:

1.
Theory of
Demand :
In the theory of demand we study the concept of individual demand and market
demand, elasticity of demand, equi-marginal principle, consumer’s surplus, etc.
2. Theory of Production : It deals with
various factors of production, production function, optimum combination of
inputs to maximize the output, returns to a variable factor and returns to
scale.
3. Theory of Price Determination : It deals with
the determination of commodity price by a firm under different market
structures.
4. Theory of factor pricing : It deals with
the determination of rent, wages, interest and profit.
Significance
of Economics:
1. Significance for academicians ; Economics
is logical and systematic science. Economic
theory explains how production takes place, how goods are exchanged and finally
consumed.
2. Significance for consumers : The ultimate
object of economics is to promote human welfare. The law of substitution, for
example, helps consumers to maximize their satisfaction from a given income.
3. Significance for the producers ; The aim of
producers is to find out the least cost combination. The study of economic
theory helps producers to choose the level of output that maximizes profits.
4. Significance in price determination : Theory of
price is the most important part of
economic theory. Pricing of products is a very difficult decision that the
firms have to take under the different market conditions. So economic theory
suggest at what time what price should be determined for a unit of commodity at
different conditions.
5. Solves problems of income distribution – Distribution of
national income among the different factors of production is the most sensitive
and difficult problem. The theory of distribution suggests that every factor
should be paid according to its marginal productivity.
6. Significance for the administrators – A successful
administration is one which offers maximum amenities to the citizens causing
the least burden on them. So a good tax-policy helps the administrator
(Government) in this regard.
7. Significance for the planners – Several
countries have adopted the technique of economic planning to accelerate the
pace of their economic growth.
LECTURE NOTES –CH 4
ELASTICITY
My Lecture Notes are written
in summary and point form- they emphasize important concepts, do not
regurgitate the book, and are consequently not meant to be a replacement of the
book- If you want to benefit from these notes you must read the book first
(before coming to class).
Learning
Outcomes
·
Understand
the meaning of elasticity of demand
·
Understand
that elasticity of demand can be with respect to income, other prices or own
prices
·
Similarly
understand the meaning of elasticity of supply, the determinants of supply
elasticity and the elasticity of supply in short and long run
·
Understand
that a tax can have different incidence on demanders and suppliers depending on
the elasticity of demand or supply
·
Understand
normal and inferior goods by examining their income elasticity
·
Understand
substitutes and complements by examining their cross price elasticity
ELASTICITY
OF DEMAND
Refers to responsiveness of demand to
changes in own price, or other determinants of demand (or factors that affect
demand).
Own
price elasticity of demand responsiveness of
demand to changes in own price
Cross
price elasticity of demand responsiveness of
demand to changes in prices of
other products.(substitutes or complements)
Income
elasticity of demand responsiveness of demand
to changes in income
h=
% change in Quantity/ % change in price
Calculating % changes and the
importance of average value of X in calculating elasticity of demand for X
The
discussion below explains that when you take % change, you can end up with two
answers, but you can get a unique answer for % change if you take the change
from the average value.
Say
X1= 20 and it increases to X2=30. What
is % change in X?
It
can be (30-20)/30 = 1/3 if we take the change with respect to new value of X
i.e. 30.
It
can be (30-20)/20= ½ if we take the
change with respect to initial value of X i.e. 20.
To
avoid this ambiguity we take % change with respect to average
value of X (i.e. the average of the initial and final values of x).
In
our example, average value of X is (initial value + new value)/2 = (20+30)/2=25
Now
after finding average value we can calculate a unique value for :
% change in
X = (new value of X-old value of X)/Av value of X
= (30-20)/ 25= 10/25
Table 4.1
Commodity
|
Reduction
in Price (Cents)
|
Increase
in Qty Demanded (per month)
|
Cheese
|
40c
per kg
|
7500
kg
|
T
Shirts
|
40c
per shirt
|
5000
shirts
|
CD
Players
|
40c
per cd player
|
100
CD players
|
Note
that the change in price is the same in absolute terms for all products i.e. 40
cents. The data is incomplete as it does
not tell us what was the original price or the original quantity demanded- all
it tells us is that what happens to demand when price falls by 40 cents
Table 4.2
Product
|
Unit
|
Original
Price ($)
1
|
New
Price ($)
2
|
Av Price
($)
3=(1+2)/2
|
Original
Quantity
4
|
New
Quantity
5
|
Av Quantity
6=(4+5)/2
|
Cheese
|
Kg
|
3.40
|
3.00
|
3.20
|
116250
|
123750
|
120000
|
T
shirts
|
Shirt
|
16.20
|
15.80
|
16.00
|
197500
|
202500
|
200000
|
CD
Players
|
Player
|
80.20
|
79.80
|
80.00
|
9950
|
10050
|
10000
|
In table 4.2 we start off with original prices
and quantities and see what happens to them once prices fall by 40 c - 116250+7500=123750
Table
4.3
Product
|
%
fall in price
(1)
|
%
increase in Qty
(2)
|
Elasticity
of demand (h)
(3)=2/1
|
Cheese
|
12.5
|
6.25
|
0.5
|
T
shirts
|
2.5
|
2.50
|
1.0
|
CD
Players
|
0.5
|
1.00
|
2.0
|
% change in price: (3.4-3)/3.2=0.4/3.2=0.125=12.5%
% change in qty:
(116250-123750)/120000=0.625=6.25%
Elasticity= 6.25/12.5=0.5
Interpreting elasticities
Demand elasticity will always have a negative value (because of
opp. signs of price and quantity in elasticity formula)
But we always take positive value (that’s an age old
convention). The higher the value the
more elastic (responsive) the demand when prices change.
See Table Extensions in theory 4.1 in L&R
(The same knowledge is represented below in alternate words)
Q. What value can the elasticity coefficient (i.e. own price
elasticity coefficient) take?
A. Value
of h is between 0 and infinity
ü When % change in Q is greater than % change in P,
demand is said to be elastic - h
will take on value of greater than 1 to infinity
ü When % change in Q is less than % change in P,
demand is said to be inelastic - h
will take on value of less than 1 or more precisely between 0 and 1
ü When Q does not change at all and P changes – elasticity is 0 (Note that while elasticity can be
+infinity, it cannot be –infinity or less than zero)
ü When % change in Q = % change in P, demand is said
to be unitary elastic
Q. Would we observe a constant own price elasticity of demand along
a demand curve?
A. Depends
on the slope of the demand curve-
Ø If D curve is a st line demand curve its
elasticity changes as we move along the curve (See fig 4-2)
Ø If D is horizontal or vertical
elasticity is infinite or zero (see fig 4-3)
Ø If D curve is a hyperbola –it will have
unitary elasticity, h=1,
((See Fig 4-3)
Determinants of Elasticity of Demand
----Depends
on availability of substitutes- if very close
substitutes are available for X, changes in prices of those goods will have a
larger effect on quantity consumed of X- Thus a product with close substitutes
tends to have an elastic demand and a product with no close substitutes tends
to have an inelastic demand
-----Depends
on how much time is available to substitute- in
SR not many products can be produced or introduced in market but over longer
run many substitutes can be developed by suppliers- Thus LR demand for a
product is more elastic than SR demand (people change their method of
transportation over time –hence demand for gasoline is less elastic in SR than
in LR)
Q. Would OPEC oil Producers experience a gain in revenues if they
restricted the cartels supply of oil and thereby increased prices?
A.
Depends on whether demand for oil is elastic or
inelastic- their revenues will only increase if demand is inelastic and revenues
would fall if demand is elastic.
Q. Can farmers increase their revenues by dropping prices?
A.
Yes only if demand is elastic (fall in price should
generate huge increase in demand such that P x Q increases. If demand is inelastic and Q does not increase
with fall in price, the total revenue to farmers P x Q would fall with a fall
in price.
These
ideas can be seen in Fig 3-5 which shows relationship \between total
revenue of firms (which is total expenditure of consumers) and quantity
demanded..
Note
that total expenditure of consumers (which is the same as total revenue of
firms producing those products) first rises with increase in quantities
purchased and then starts falling despite the fact that more quantities are
still being purchased. Note that up to
10,000 units of demand the expenditure is rising and then after 10000 units it
starts to fall and goes to zero at 20000 units of consumption demand.
Q. Why may this be so?
A.
The expenditure PQ is composed of prices and quantities – therefore DTE=
DP x DQ. Along the demand curve prices are throughout
falling and quantities are throughout rising so direction of change of TE is
inderminate. However, the answer lies in
understanding that elasticity of demand (or response of demand to changes in price)
is different over the initial range (top LHS) of the demand curve as compared
to the latter part (bottom RHS) of the D curve.
Initially
the increase in demand is much more than the fall in price so that TE rises- in
other words over the initial range of the demand curve demand is more elastic
(i.e. change in demand is more than change in price). We note that TEs continually increase till
P=2 and D=10000, but after that further fall in prices does not lead to much
larger increase in demand (i.e. fall in P is greater than increase in D,
therefore TE=PQ falls).
Note
that in absolute value demand is continually increasing with fall in prices but
at prices less than P=2, the incremental increase in demand is less than the
incremental decrease in price. In other words at P less than 2 Demand keeps
becoming more and more inelastic. The
effect of this demand inelasticity is that TE eventually becomes zero when
D=20,000 units.
Price Elasticity of Supply
Fig 4-6
Measures
the elasticity of supply of goods with respect to changes in market
prices.
It
is denoted hs = %
change in quantity supplied
% change in
market price
The
sign of hs is positive because both numerator and denominator
are always positive. The reason that
numerator and denominator are both positive is that we are considering the
supply curves which have positive slopes.
However,
there are special cases of supply curves whose slopes may not be positive-they
could be vertical or horizontal. A very
steep S curve means that a unit increase (decrease) in price has a very small
increase (increase) in Q supplied. It means steeper S curve is less elastic or
inelastic.
Vertical
S curve has hs = 0, steeper S curves will have small values of
elasticity of supply
Horizontal
S curve-has hs =¥, flatter S curves will have large values of
elasticity of supply
Special
case of S curve::: Any positively sloped S curve passing through origin will
have hs = 1.
Look
at smaller triangle and larger triangle-their angles are equal (similar
triangles) therefore ratios of their sides are equal
p/q= Dp/Dq
and
we know from definition that hs
= Dq/q
Dp/p
=
Dq/Dp
. p/q
Substitute
for p/q = Dq/Dp
. Dp/Dq
= 1
(means that the % change in quantity supplied equals the % change in
price)
Determinants of Supply
Elasticity?
Depends
on how easy it is to substitute factors of production towards the prodn of
those goods whose price has risen. Naturally we will not see this substitution
in very diverse products cars and cabbages etc, rather close products e.g
different kinds of detergents or soaps or other very close substitutes-
How
quickly S responds to increase the prodn of the product whose P has risen
depends on whether the costs will also rise as substitution in prodn is made-
if that’s the case then supply may not be responsive to increase in price.
Generally
in SR supply is not that responsive as compared to LR when costs can be better
controlled and factors of prodn can be better combined to produce the product
whose price has risen. Therefore SR S
curves are relatively inelastic compared to LR S curves. (see Fig 4-7)
An Example Where Elasticity
Matters (pg 81) Fig 4-8
We
are interested to find out who bears a higher burden when a tax is imposed i.e.
the consumers or the sellers.
When
we say higher burden we mean who bears the loss when a tax is imposed. For example how much of the tax can be passed
on to consumers and how much is absorbed will determine who eventually bears
the burden of the tax.
The
more inelastic the demand curve relative to the supply curve the more burden of
a tax will be borne by consumers – This fact is demonstrated in Fig 4-9, but
ideas pertaining to “seller price”, “consumer price” and “shift of supply
curve” due to excise tax should first be understood through fig 4-8.
Explanation
of Fig 4-9
In
Fig 4-9 (i) Supply is elastic and demand is inelastic (relative elasticities
matter)
Tax
levied :
Consumption
or demand falls and P rises. Previously Consumer was spending P0Q0 and now PcQ1
.
S
falls too- previously suppliers were earning P0Q0 now they earn PcQ1- because
price jumps from p0 to pc and D falls from q0 to q1.
Note
that consumers’ expenditure has increased much more due to huge rise in price
and less drop in quantities- that’s because their demand is inelastic for
cigarettes. On the other hand the price
for suppliers does not fall as much because of the larger elasticity of their
supply curves, hence their new revenue PsQ1 is not much less than previous
revenue (p0q0)
Conclusion: Due to inelastic D curve, the price rises much more for
consumer and quantity falls less, therefore the consumer ends up paying much
more for their consumption – thus in other words the burden of the excise tax
falls more on the consumer.
In
Fig 4-9 (ii) a tax of $t per pack of cigarettes shifts up the S curve by $t for
each and every quantity of cigarette packs. At the higher price of pc consumers
only demand q1 packs of cigarettes. Firms are willing to supply q1 demand at
price of ps. Note that in the case of elastic D for consumers (it must be the
case that they have more substitution possibilities) they are able to
drastically reduce their Demand and cut down conspn to q1 from q0.
So
while prices per pack have increased by
the same amount in case (i) and (ii) [How? Note that the tax in case (i) is
the same as tax in case (ii) –the shift up of the S curve is the same], the larger reduction in quantity Demanded in
case (ii) prevents the consumers bill from going up too much- Note that in case
(i) when demand was inelastic (perhaps not many substitutes were available to
consumer), the consumer was not able to reduce demand much in response to the
excise tax per pack of cigarettes. Consequently his total bill, P.Q went up
(%reduction in quantity was less than the % increase in prices)- thus in case
(i) the burden of the tax was higher than in case (ii).
Conclusion: Due to elastic Demand quantity falls much more and
price rises much less, therefore less burden falls on consumer.
Payroll Taxes- Applying Eco
Concepts 4-2
–p 84 L&R
Payroll taxes are deducted from a persons income. Payroll tax
different from income tax which we pay at the end of fiscal year for tax
assessment purposes to Revenue Canada.
Payroll taxes are deducted from each salary slip by employer. This tax is then
deposited by employer to Revenue Canada.
Who gains and who loses by thee payroll taxes?
The
effects of this tax (like excise tax) will be on both prices and quantities. In
this case the quantity is quantity of employment and prices are wages (hourly
wages) of workers.
A
payroll tax deducted by employer drives a wedge between the wage paid by firm
(Wf) and wage received by worker (Ww).
When
there was no payroll tax the employment was E0 and wage was w0.
With
payroll tax, firms have to pay $t/hr to govt. in addition to what they pay to
workers.
What happens to employment?
Note
that with a rise in wages from w0 to wf (wf-w0 is rise in firms net cost per
hour per worker), firms would hire only E1 workers (along their Demand curve
for labor). It can be seen that the employment has fallen from E0 to E1.
In this example who bears most of the burden of the tax- firms or
labor?
The
burden of the tax is determined by how much the wage falls for workers as
compared to the increase in the wage (net cost per worker) for firms. With an inelastic Supply curve for labor,
workers do not have much option, but to keep working. Hence at lower employment
of E1, the wage received by workers falls a lot from the previous level of Wo
(note that if S was elastic wage would not have fallen as much when firms
reduced their demand for labor). Thus
burden of payroll tax is more on workers and less on firms due to the relative
inelasticity of labor supply as compared to labor demand by firms.
Conclusion: Payroll taxes increase net cost of hiring for firms and
reduce net wages for labor- naturally with higher wages firms hire less, than
would be the case without any payroll taxes.
What Determines Income
Elasticity (discussion of income consumption curves)
hY = % change in quantity demanded
% change in income
↑
Y → ↑ D --- for normal goods; therefore hY
≥ 0
↑
Y → ↓ D --- for inferior goods; therefore hY ≤ 0
Income
elasticity of Normal Goods will definitely be positive (greater than 0) but can
be greater than unity (elastic) or less than unity (inelastic) depending on
whether the change in Q demanded is greater or less than the change in income..
If hY is
greater than 1, we say that demand is income elastic
If hY is
less than 1, we say that demand is income inelastic
Defining Inferior and Normal Goods in terms of Elasticity (See table 4-4 for
examples of such goods and their empirically observed elasticities)
Inferior Goods have hY
less than zero
Normal Goods which are inelastic have hY
between zero and one
Normal Goods which are elastic have hY
greater than one
Income Consumption
Curves (Fig 4-10)
Fig 4-10 shows the
effects of change of income on quantity demanded- these curves can have
different shapes depending on their income elasticity.
Explanation of Fig
4-10:
Normal goods increase
in quantity as income increases – slope is rising upwards Fig 4-10 (i)
Luxury goods (which
are also normal goods as opposed to being inferior goods) also increase in
quantity as income rises- however there is a difference between normal goods
which are necessities and normal goods which are luxuries. In the case of
necessities, quantity increases no doubt but at a decreasing rate (How much
necessities can you have with high income), however in the case of luxuries the
higher the income increases thee more we consume luxuries; hence the ICC will
have an increasing slope (note that’s the case after I1 income). See
Fig 4-10 (ii)
In the case of
inferior goods quantity reduces beyond a certain income- thus a commodity may
be a necessity at lower incomes (say potatoes) but becomes an inferior good at
higher incomes, and after we have achieved that income level we reduce its
consumption. See Fig 4-10 (iii)
Cross Elasticity of Demand
hxy = % change in Q
demanded of X---
% change in price of good Y
- ¥ ≤hxy ≤ ¥
If cross elasticity is
>0 it’s a substitute – that is ↑ in price of Y leads to ↑ in D for X –
Demand curve of X will shift right
If cross elasticity is
<0 it’s a complement – that is ↑ in price of Y leads to ↓in D for X – Demand
curve of X will shift left
CHAPTER 5: ELASTICITY (SEE QUIZ #3 AND EXCEL #2; recommended
problems and notes)
MULTIPLE
CHOICE
1. Point elasticity measures elasticity:
a.
|
over
a given range of a function.
|
b.
|
at
a spot on a function.
|
c.
|
over
a given range along a function.
|
d.
|
before
non-price effects.
|
ANS: B
2. Arc elasticity is measured:
a.
|
over
a given range of a function.
|
b.
|
at
a spot on a function.
|
c.
|
over
a given range along a function.
|
d.
|
before
non-price effects.
|
ANS: C
3. With elastic demand, a price increase will:
a.
|
decrease
marginal revenue.
|
b.
|
decrease
total revenue.
|
c.
|
increase
total revenue.
|
d.
|
decrease
marginal revenue and total revenue.
|
ANS: B
4. With unitary elasticity of demand, a price
increase will:
a.
|
be
associated with zero marginal revenue.
|
b.
|
decrease
total revenue.
|
c.
|
increase
total revenue.
|
d.
|
decrease
marginal and total revenue.
|
ANS: A
5. The demand for a product tends to be
inelastic if:
a.
|
it
is expensive.
|
b.
|
a
small proportion of consumer's income is spent on the good.
|
c.
|
consumers
are quick to respond to price changes.
|
d.
|
it
has many substitutes.
|
ANS: B
6. Two products are complements if the:
a.
|
cross-price
elasticity of demand is less than zero.
|
b.
|
cross-price
elasticity of demand equals zero.
|
c.
|
cross-price
elasticity of demand is greater than zero.
|
d.
|
price
elasticity of demand for each good is greater than zero.
|
ANS: A
7. If the income elasticity of demand for
a good is greater than one, the good is:
a.
|
a
noncyclical normal good.
|
b.
|
a
cyclical normal good.
|
c.
|
neither
a normal nor an inferior good.
|
d.
|
an
inferior good.
|
ANS: B
8. When the product demand curve is Q =
140 - 10P, and price is decreased from P1 = $10 to P2 =
$9, the arc price elasticity of demand is:
a.
|
-0.1
|
b.
|
-3
|
c.
|
-4
|
d.
|
-10
|
ANS: B
9. If the point price elasticity of demand
equals -2 and the marginal cost per unit is $5, the optimal price is:
a.
|
$5
|
b.
|
$10
|
c.
|
$2
|
d.
|
impossible
to determine without further information.
|
ANS: B
10. The concept of cross-price elasticity is
used to examine the responsiveness of demand:
a.
|
to
changes in income.
|
b.
|
for
one product to changes in the price of another.
|
c.
|
to
changes in "own" price.
|
d.
|
to
changes in income.
|
ANS: B
11. When the cross-price elasticity
= 3:

a.
|
demand
rises by 3% with a 1% increase in the price of X.
|
b.
|
the
quantity demanded rises by 3% with a 1% increase in the price of X.
|
c.
|
the
quantity demanded rises by 1% with a 3% increase in the price of X.
|
d.
|
demand
rises by 1% with a 3% increase in the price of X.
|
ANS: A
PROBLEMS
12. Elasticity. The demand for mini
cassette players can be characterized by the following point elasticities:
price elasticity = -2, cross-price elasticity with AA Alkaline batteries =
-1.5, and income elasticity = 3. Indicate whether each of the following
statements is true or false, and explain your answer.
A.
|
A
price increase for cassette players will decrease both the number of units
demanded and the total revenue of sellers.
|
|
|
B.
|
The
cross-price elasticity indicates that a 2% reduction in the price of cassette
players will cause a 3% increase in battery demand.
|
|
|
C.
|
Demand
for cassette players is price elastic and they are cyclical normal goods.
|
|
|
D.
|
Falling
battery prices will definitely increase revenues received by sellers of both
cassette players and batteries.
|
|
|
E.
|
A
3% price reduction in cassette players would be necessary to overcome the
effects of a 2% decline in income.
|
ANS:
A.
|
True.
A price increase will always decrease units sold, given a downward sloping
demand curve. The negative sign on the price elasticity indicates that this
is indeed the case here. The fact that price elasticity equals -2 indicates
that demand is elastic with respect to price, and therefore that a price
increase will also decrease total revenues.
|
|
|
B.
|
False.
The cross-price elasticity indicates that a 2% decrease in the price of
batteries will have the effect of increasing cassette player demand by 3%.
|
|
|
C.
|
True.
Demand is price elastic (see part a). Because the income elasticity is positive,
cassette players are a normal good. Moreover, because the income elasticity
is greater than one, cassette player demand is also cyclical.
|
|
|
D.
|
False.
A negative cross-price elasticity indicates that cassette players and
batteries are compliments. Therefore, falling battery prices will increase
the demand for cassette players and resulting revenues for sellers. However,
we have no information concerning the price elasticity of demand for
batteries, and therefore do not know the effect of falling battery prices on
battery revenues.
|
|
|
E.
|
True.
A 3% reduction in price will cause a 6% increase in the quantity of cassette
players demanded. A 2% decline in income will cause a 6% fall in demand.
These changes will be mutually offsetting.
|
13. Demand Analysis. The Crank
Yankers DVD (season two) has been a hot seller during recent weeks. An analysis
of weekly demand shows:
Q =
3,000 - 90P
where
Q is DVD sales and P is price.
A.
|
How
many DVDs could be sold at a $20 price?
|
|
|
B.
|
Calculate
the point price elasticity of demand at a price of $20.
|
ANS:
A.
|
Q
= 3,000 - 90P
|
|
= 3,000 - 90(20)
|
|
= 1,200
|
|
|
B.
|
The
point price elasticity of demand at a price of $20 is calculated as follows:
|
|
![]() |
|
= -90
![]() |
|
= -1.5 (elastic)
|
14. Optimal Price.
Last week, Discount Food Stores, Inc. reduced the average price on the 22 ounce
size of Dishwashing Liquid by 1%. In response, sales jumped by 8%.
A.
|
Calculate
the point price elasticity of demand for Dishwashing Liquid.
|
|
|
B.
|
Calculate
the optimal price for Dishwashing Liquid if marginal cost is 70¢ per unit.
|
ANS:
A.
|
![]() |
|
=
![]() |
|
= -8 (elastic)
|
|
|
B.
|
The
optimal price is found setting MC = MR and solving for P where:
|
|
MC
= MR = P
![]() |
|
0.7
= P
![]() |
|
0.7
= 0.875P
|
|
P
= 0.8 or 80¢
|
15. Arc Price Elasticity.
Assume that amazon.com dropped the price on a men's Seiko watch (SGF719) from
$120 to $60, and sales jumped from 50 to 100 units per day.
A.
|
Calculate
the implied arc price elasticity of demand.
|
|
|
B.
|
Is
a further price decrease warranted? Why or why not?
|
ANS:
A.
|
![]() |
|
=
![]() |
|
= -1
|
|
|
B.
|
No
further price decrease is warranted. At P = $60, the EP = -1. This
means that $60 is the revenue-maximizing price and any further decrease in
price would cause demand to fall into the inelastic region of the demand
curve. In the inelastic region of the demand curve prices are too low because
both revenues and profits would rise with an increase in price.
|
16. Income Elasticity. Deluxe
Carpeting, Inc., is a leading manufacturer of stain-resistant carpeting. Demand
for Deluxe products is tied to the overall pace of building and remodeling
activity and, therefore, is sensitive to changes in national income. The carpet
manufacturing industry is highly competitive, so Deluxe's demand is also very
price-sensitive.
During
the past year, Deluxe sold 28 million square yards (units) of carpeting at an
average wholesale price of $16 per unit. This year, GNP per capita is expected
to fall from $19,000 to $17,000 as the nation enters a steep recession. Without
any price change, Deluxe expects current-year sales to fall to 20 million
units.
A.
|
Calculate
the implied arc income elasticity of demand.
|
|
|
B.
|
Given
the projected fall in income, the sales manager believes that current volume
of 28 million units could only be maintained with a price cut of $2 per unit.
On this basis, calculate the implied arc price elasticity of demand.
|
|
|
C.
|
Holding
all else equal, would a further increase in price result in higher or lower
total revenue?
|
ANS:
A.
|
![]() |
|
=
![]() |
|
= 3
|
|
|
B.
|
Without
a price decrease, sales this year would total 20 million units. Therefore, it
is appropriate to estimate the arc price elasticity from a
(before-price-decrease) base of 20 million units:
|
|
![]() |
|
=
![]() |
|
= -2.5 (elastic)
|
|
|
C.
|
Lower.
Because carpet demand is in the elastic range, EP = -2.5, an
increase (decrease) in price will result in lower (higher) total revenues.
|
CHAPTER 6: FORECASTING (SEE Ch.6 on line questions and Quiz #4 and
notes)
17. A forecast method based on the informed
opinion of several individuals is called:
a.
|
personal
insight.
|
b.
|
panel
consensus.
|
c.
|
the
Delphi method.
|
d.
|
qualitative
analysis.
|
ANS: B
18. A rhythmic annual pattern in sales or
profits is called:
a.
|
cyclical
fluctuation.
|
b.
|
secular
trend.
|
c.
|
trend
analysis.
|
d.
|
seasonal
variation.
|
ANS: D
19. Growth trend analysis assumes:
a.
|
constant
unit change over time.
|
b.
|
irregular
percentage change over time.
|
c.
|
sporadic
unit change over time.
|
d.
|
constant
percentage change over time.
|
ANS:
D
CHAPTER 7:
PRODUCTION (See Quiz #4; recommended problems and notes)
20. The law of diminishing returns:
a.
|
deals
specifically with the diminishing marginal product of fixed input factors.
|
b.
|
states
that the marginal product of a variable factor must eventually decline as increasingly
more is employed.
|
c.
|
can
be derived deductively.
|
d.
|
states
that as the quantity of a variable input increases, with the quantities of
all other factors being held constant, the resulting output must eventually
diminish.
|
ANS: B
22. When PX = $60, MPX
= 5 and MPY = 2, relative employment levels are optimal provided:
a.
|
PY
= 16.7¢.
|
b.
|
PY
= $24.
|
c.
|
PY
= $60.
|
d.
|
PY
= $150.
|
ANS: B
23. When PX = $100, MPX
= 10 and MRQ = $5, the marginal revenue product of X equals:
a.
|
$100.
|
b.
|
$50.
|
c.
|
$10.
|
d.
|
$5.
|
ANS: B
24. Total output is maximized when:
a.
|
average
product equals zero.
|
b.
|
marginal
product is maximized.
|
c.
|
average
product is maximized.
|
d.
|
marginal
product equals zero.
|
ANS: D
25. A firm will maximize profits by
employing the quantity of each input where the marginal:
a.
|
revenue
product of each input equals its price.
|
b.
|
revenue
equals the price of each input.
|
c.
|
product
of each input is equal.
|
d.
|
product
of each input equals its price.
|
ANS: A
26. Optimal Input Mix. Hydraulics Ltd. has designed a pipeline
that provides a throughput of 70,000 gallons of water per 24-hour period. If
the diameter of the pipeline were increased by 1 inch, throughput would
increase by 4,000 gallons per day. Alternatively, throughput could be increased
by 6,000 gallons per day using the original pipe diameter with pumps that had
100 more horsepower.
|
|
B.
|
Assuming
the cost of additional pump size is $600 per horsepower and the cost of
larger diameter pipe is $200,000 per inch, does the original design exhibit
the property required for optimal input combinations? If so, why? If not, why
not?
|
ANS:
B.
|
No.
The rule for optimal input proportions is:
|
|
![]() ![]() |
|
|
|
In
this instance the question is:
|
|
![]() ![]() ![]() |
|
![]() ![]() ![]() |
|
0.02
![]() |
|
|
|
Here
the additional throughput provided by the last dollar spent on more
horsepower (0.10 gallons/day) is five times the gain in output resulting from
the last dollar spent to increase the pipe diameter (0.02 gallons/day). Thus,
horsepower and pipe diameter are not being employed in optimal proportions in
this situation.
|
27. Optimal Input Level. U-Do-It Furniture, Inc., sells
hardwood chairs, in both kits and fully assembled forms. Customers who assemble
their own chairs benefit from the lower kit price of $35 per chair. "Full-service"
customers enjoy the luxury of an assembled chair, but pay a higher price of $60
per chair. Both kit and fully assembled chair prices are stable. The company
has observed the following relation between the number of assembly workers
employed per day and assembled chair output:
Number
of
Workers
per
day
|
Finished
Chairs
|
0
|
0
|
1
|
5
|
2
|
9
|
3
|
12
|
4
|
14
|
5
|
15
|
A.
|
Construct
a table showing the net marginal revenue product derived from assembly worker
employment.
|
|
|
B.
|
How
many assemblers would U-Do-It Furniture employ at a daily wage rate of $75?
|
|
|
C.
|
What
is the highest daily wage rate U-Do-It Furniture would pay to hire four
assemblers per day?
|
ANS:
A.
|
Because
the market for hardwood chairs is perfectly competitive, the $25 price
premium for fully assembled chairs versus kits is stable. Thus, the net
marginal revenue product of assembler labor (sometimes referred to as the
value of marginal product) is:
|
||||
|
|
||||
|
Number
of
Assemblers
per
Day
(1)
|
Fully
Assembled
Output
(2)
|
Marginal
Product
of
Labor
(3)
|
Net
Marginal
Revenue
Product
of
Labor
(4)=(3)$25
|
|
|
0
|
0
|
--
|
--
|
|
|
1
|
5
|
5
|
$125
|
|
|
2
|
9
|
4
|
100
|
|
|
3
|
12
|
3
|
75
|
|
|
4
|
14
|
2
|
50
|
|
|
5
|
15
|
1
|
25
|
|
|
|
||||
B.
|
From
the table above, we see that employment of three assemblers could be
justified at a daily wage of $75 because MRPA=3 = $75. Employment
of a fourth assembler could not be justified because MRPA=4 = $50
< $75.
|
||||
|
|
||||
C.
|
From
the table above, the MRPA=4 = $50. Thus, a daily wage of $50 per
assembler is the most U-Do-It Furniture would be willing to pay to hire a staff
of 4 assemblers.
|
CHAPTER 8: COST
AND ESTIMATION (Use recommended problems and notes)
28. Breakeven.
Three graduate business students are considering operating a tofu burger stand
in the Dalles, Oregon, windsurfing resort area during their
summer break. This is an alternative to summer employment with a local fruit
cannery where they would earn $7,500 each over the three-month summer period. A
fully equipped facility can be leased at a cost of $8,000 for the summer.
Additional projected costs are $2,000 for insurance, and 25¢ per unit for
materials and supplies. Their tofu burgers would be priced at $1.50 per unit.
|
|
C.
|
What
is the economic breakeven number of units for this operation? (Assume a $1.50
price and ignore interest costs associated with the timing of the lease
payments.)
|
ANS
C.
|
The
economic breakeven point is reached when:
|
|
Q
=
![]() |
|
=
![]() |
|
= 26,000 units
|
29. Profit Contribution Analysis. Ben Laden Rugs, Inc., sells
hand-made cotton rugs to tourists at a price of $50. Of this amount, $40 is
profit contribution. Ben Laden is considering an attempt to differentiate his
product from several other competitors by using high quality natural herb dyes.
Doing so would increase Ben Laden's unit cost by $15 per rug. Current annual
profits are $35,000 on 1,000 rug sales.
A.
|
Assuming
average variable costs are constant at all output levels, what is Ben Laden's
total cost function before the proposed change?
|
|
|
B.
|
What
will the total cost function be if high quality natural herb dyes are used?
|
|
|
C.
|
Assume
rug prices remain stable at $50. What percentage increase in sales would be
necessary to maintain current profit levels?
|
ANS:
A.
|
From
the definition of profit contribution we know that on a per unit basis:
|
|
|
|
Profit
contribution = P - AVC
|
|
$40
= $50 - AVC
|
|
AVC
= $10 per unit
|
|
|
|
Total
fixed cost for Ben Laden can be calculated as follows:
|
|
|
|
= TR - TC
|
|
= TR - TVC - TFC
|
|
= (P Q) - (AVC Q) - TFC
|
|
$35,000
= $50(1,000) - $10(1,000) - TFC
|
|
$35,000
= $40,000 - TFC
|
|
TFC
= $5,000
|
|
|
|
Therefore,
the total cost function is:
|
|
TC
= TFC + (AVC Q)
|
|
TC
= $5,000 + $10Q
|
B.
|
By
using high quality natural herb dyes, Ben Laden's variable cost would
increase by $15 while its fixed costs remain the same. Ben Laden's new total
cost function would be:
|
|
|
|
TC
= $5,000 + $10Q + $15Q
|
|
TC
= $5,000 + $25Q
|
C.
|
The
new number of rug sales necessary to maintain current profit levels would be:
|
|
|
|
= (P Q) - (AVC Q) - TFC
|
|
$35,000
= $50Q - $25Q - $5,000
|
|
25Q
= 40,000
|
|
Q
= 1,600
|
|
Percentage
increase in Q =
![]() |
|
|
|
Thus,
a 60% increase in rug sales would be needed to maintain current profit
levels.
|
Elasticity
of demand:
Elasticity of demand refers to Price elasticity of demand. It
responsiveness demand of a goods with
the change in price.
Coefficient of Price Elasticity of
demand = (Ed)= ( % change in
demand) / (% change in price)
Value
of Ed
|
Interpretation
|
Ed
= 0
|
Perfectly
inelastic demand (Demand curve is perpendicular to x-axis)
|
-1
< Ed < 0
|
Inelastic demand
|
Ed
< -1
|
Elastic
demand
|
Ed
= - ∞
|
Perfectly
elastic demand (Demand curve is
parallel to x-axis)
|
Cross
Price- Elasticity of Demand: This
measures the responsiveness of the demand of a goods A to a price change of other goods B (even if
price of A remains unchanged).
Coefficient
of Cross Price-Elasticity of Demand of A due to price change in B is
EA,B = (% change in demand of A) / (% change
in price of B)
EA,B < 0: If two goods A and B are complimentary goods
then Coefficient of Cross Price-Elasticity of Demand will be negative. i.e. if
price of one goods increases then demand of its complimentary goods falls. For example Cars and petrol are complimentary
goods. If price of petrol increases then demand of car falls.
EA,B > 0: If two goods A
and B are substitutes then Coefficient of Cross Price-Elasticity of Demand is
positive. i.e. if price of one goods increases then demand of its substitute
increases and vice-versa. For example,
Beef and Chicken are substitutes.
EA,B =0 : Two goods A and B are independent
and price change in B does not affect the demand of A.
Income
elasticity of Demand: This measures the responsiveness of demand of
goods to the change in income of the consumers.
Coefficient
of income elasticity of demand = EI = (% change in demand) / (%
change in real income)
EI
<0 :
Coefficient of income elasticity of demand is negative for inferior goods. It
means if income of consumer increases then demand of inferior goods fall (as
consumer would opt for better goods if they are richer).
1>EI
> 0 :
Coefficient of income elasticity of demand is positive for normal goods. It
means if income of consumer increases then demand of a normal goods increases.
EI
>1 : For
luxury goods or superior goods, Coefficient of income elasticity of demand is greater than 1.
EI
=0 : Increase
in income does not affect the demand of Sticky goods and hence Coefficient of
income elasticity of demand of sticky goods is zero.
Significance of differences among the three terms
Price
elasticity of demand measures responsiveness of the demand of a goods A with
the change in price of A only. So when producer is interested in knowing what
will be the effect of the price change
on the demand of the goods they produce, they will be interested in Price
elasticity of demand.
On
the other hand cross-price elasticity of demand measures the responsiveness of
the demand of goods with the change in price of some other goods B. It reflects
how goods A’s demand depends on goods B. Cross price elasticity is useful in
determining if two products are substitutes, complementary or
independent and the degree of dependence of demand of one product on other.
The Income elasticity of demand does not deal
with price. It measures the responsiveness of the demand with the change in
income of the consumer. Income elasticity is also helpful in determining if the
product is inferior goods, superior goods, sticky goods or normal goods.
Relationship
between Total Revenue and Elasticity of demand:
We
see in the graph that Total revenue increases as quantity demanded increases
from 1 to 4. Somewhere between quantity demanded 4 and 5, Total revenue curve
start declining. After that point, as quantity demanded increases, Total
revenue curve declines sharply.
Now,
let us calculate price elasticity of demand:
Quantity
Demanded
|
Price
|
PED=
(∆Q/Q)/( ∆P/P)
|
1
|
80
|
----
|
2
|
70
|
-3.5
|
3
|
60
|
-2
|
4
|
50
|
-1.25
|
5
|
40
|
-0.8
|
6
|
30
|
-0.5
|
7
|
20
|
-0.286
|
8
|
10
|
-0.125
|
We see that that from quantity
demanded is 1 to 4, absolute value of PED is greater than 1. So this is elastic
zone. In elastic zone Total Revenue increases as price decreases as percentage
change in quantity demanded is higher than the percentage change in price.
Somewhere between quantity demanded 4
and 5, absolute value of PED becomes 1
which is Unit-elastic point. At this point, the percentage change in quantity
is equal to the percentage change in price and hence price change does not
affect the revenue.
After
this point, as price decreases,
absolute value of PED becomes less than 1 which is inelastic zone. In inelastic
zone, total revenue decreases as price decreases as percentage change in
quantity demanded is less than percentage change in price.
10. Elasticities
Essay
1. What is price
elasticity of demand? Describe the three
ranges of elasticity and their relationship to marginal revenue.
Problems
2. Given
appropriate information, calculate the arc price, income, and cross-price
elasticities of demand and identify.
3. Given
appropriate information, calculate the point price, income, and cross-price
elasticities of demand and identify.
Price
Elasticity of Demand
When a firm is thinking about setting its
price, the responsiveness of quantity demanded to price is very important. The law of demand states that if the relative
price of a good rises, the quantity demanded falls. But by how much? If the amount buyers are able and willing to
buy is very responsive to changes in the good’s price, then buyers will
purchase much less. If it isn’t very
responsive, then they will buy about the same amount—only a little bit less.
The term used in economics to refer to
this responsiveness is elasticity.
Price elasticity of demand is the percent
change in quantity demanded divided by the
percent change in the good’s price.
There
are two measures of elasticity.
Arc price elasticity of demand Ep= Q2‑Q1/P2‑P1 * P2+P1/Q2+Q1
Point Price elasticity of demand Ep = first derivative of the demand function * P/Q
Qd=65060-20P
derivative = -20
point
price elasticity of demand function = -20P/Q
Suppose the price is 2753. Using the demand function, quantity is
10,000. The point price elasticity of
demand is:
Ep
= -20 * P/Q
= -20 * 2753/10,000
= -5.51
If you are given two prices and the
associated quantities demanded, then the arc elasticity of demand can be
calculated:
P Qd
500 249,500
550 248,500
Ep
= (249,500 – 248,500)/(500-550) *
(500+550)/(249500+248500)
=
1000/-50 * 1050/498,000
= -20 *
.002108
=
-.04217
If you are just given two prices and a
demand function, arc elasticity of demand can still be found. First, however, you must substitute the two
prices into the demand function and find the quantity demanded.
Ranges of Elasticity
Inelastic‑elasticity is
less than one (in absolute value)
Inelastic
means that a change in price causes a less than proportional change in quantity
demanded. For example, a 1%
increase in price causes a less than one percent decrease in quantity demanded.
If demand is inelastic then a higher
price raises revenue even though less is sold.
And a lower price means less revenue, even though more units are
sold.
If demand is inelastic, then marginal
revenue is negative. That means an
increase in output results in lower revenue and a decrease in quantity leads to
more revenue. That’s because a bit
more output goes with a lower price and even though more units are sold, the
lower price for each unit causes less revenue.
Elastic-elasticity is
greater than one in absolute value.
Elastic means that a change in price causes a more than proportional
change in quantity demanded. For
example, a 1% increase in price causes a more than 1% decrease in quantity
demanded.
If demand is elastic, then a higher
price lowers revenue and a lower price raises revenue. Even though more is earned for each unit
when the price rises, the number of units sold drops so much that revenue is
less. And a lower price raises revenue
because so many more units are sold even though less is made per unit.
If demand is elastic, marginal revenue
is positive. A larger output is
associated with more revenue and a smaller output with less revenue.
Unit Elastic - elasticity
is equal to one in absolute value.
Unit elastic means that a change in
price causes a proportionate change in quantity demanded. For example, a 1% increase in price leads to
a 1% decrease in quantity demanded.
If demand is unit elastic, then a
higher or lower price leaves revenue unchanged. An increase in price generates more
revenue per unit, but the proportionate decrease in units sold leaves revenue
unchanged.
If demand is unit elastic, then marginal
revenue is equal to zero. If quantity
increases, there are more units sold, but the lower price per unit leaves
revenue unchanged.
Perfectly Inelastic
Elasticity is equal to zero. This implies that a change in price has no
impact on quantity demanded. It is
inconsistent with the law of demand.
Perfectly Elastic
Elasticity is infinite. An increase in price, no matter how small,
causes quantity demanded to fall to zero.
A decrease in price, no matter how small, causes quantity demanded to
rise to infinity. While literally not
possible, a small firm in a large market selling a product identical to those
of its competitors might perceive itself in this position. Any increase in price above what the others’
charge will result in no sales.
Lowering the price would not literally result in infinite sales, but
charging less than the going price will result in more orders than can possibly
be filled.
Income
Elasticities
Income elasticity of demand looks at the
responsiveness of demand to changes in income.
It is the percent change in quantity over the percent change in income.
Arc
income elasticity
Arc
income elasticity of demand is calculated when given two different levels of
income and the quantity demanded at each income level.
Ey=
Qd2‑Qd1/y2‑y1 * y2+y1/Qd2+Qd1
Example:
Y Qd
7100
249500
7200
270000
Epy
= (249500-270000)/(7100-7200) *
(7100+7200)/(249500+270000)
=
5.64
Point Income Elasticity
Point
income elasticity of demand is calculated when there is a demand function.
Ey
= first derivative of the demand function with respect to income * y/Q
Qd
= -20,000 ‑ 20P + .5A^.5 - 50Pc +.1Ps + 5Y
derivative = 5
point income elasticity = 5y/Q (plug in the
value of income and quantity demanded.)
Ey
= 5*9000/10,000
= 4.5
income
elasticity greater than zero--normal good
income
elasticity less than zero--inferior good
income
elasticity greater than one--luxury
income
elasticity less than one--necessity
Generally, economists define a normal
good as one with a negative income elasticity of demand. If income rises, then quantity demanded
falls and that’s it. While we say that
such goods are lower quality and give those sorts of example, the defining
characteristic is what happens to demand when income changes.
Similarly, in income elasticity of
demand is positive, then the good is normal, regardless of ones opinion about
its quality.
In economics, a luxury is defined as a
good with an income elasticity of demand greater than one. That means that a change in income leads to
a more than proportional change in quantity demanded. If income rises, quantity demanded rises
more than in proportion. If income
falls, quantity demanded falls more than in proportion.
In economics, a necessity is a good with
income elasticity of demand less than one (but greater than zero. Inferior goods aren’t generally considered
necessities.) If income should rise,
demand for a necessity rises, but less than in proportion to the increase in
income. And vice versa.
Cross Price Elasticity of Demand
Cross-price elasticity demand looks at the
responsiveness of the demand for a good to the price of some other good. It is the percent change in quantity of the
good divided by the percent change in quantity of some other goods price. The formulas look similar to ordinary price
elasticity of demand--
Arc
elasticity Ep= Q2‑Q1/Po2‑Po1 * Po2+Po1/Q2+Q1
point
elasticity Ep = first derivative of the demand function with respect to some
other good * Po/Q
Again, this must be done using the demand
function, not the simple one.
Qd
= -20,000 ‑ 20P + .5A^.5 - 50Pc +.1Ps + 5Y
Lets
do Pc
derivative =
-50
point
cross price elasticity = -50Pc /Q (plug in the value of the other
goods price and quantity demanded of the good we are working with.)
Epc
= -50*6/10000
= -.03
cross price
elasticity greater than zero, the goods are substitutes
cross price
elasticity less than zero, the goods are complements.
Again, economists define substitute and
complement according to these relationships.
If the increase in another goods price leads to an increase in the
demand for the good, then they are substitutes. While the rationale is that somehow people
can use one good instead of another, there is no need to see some obvious way
in which people might do this. While we
use examples like rice crispies and corn flakes, it doesn’t have to be that
obvious.
Complements are the same. If an increase in another goods price leads
to a lower demand for the good, then they are complements. The idea is that the goods are somehow used
together. And while we give examples
like milk and cereal, no such obvious relationship is necessary—just the relationship
between the price and quantity demanded.

CHECKPOINT
5.1 Price Elasticity of Demand
1a. The percentage change in price is 8 percent. The midpoint method
shows the percentage is 

1b. The percentage change in quantity is 4 percent. The midpoint method
shows the percentage is 

1c. The demand for Internet services is inelastic
because the percentage change in quantity demanded is less than the percentage
change in price.
1d. The demand for AOL service is more elastic
than the demand for Internet service because more substitutes exist for AOL
service in particular than for Internet service in general. AOL service is a
more narrowly defined service.
1e. The price elasticity of demand = (4 percent) ÷
(8 percent) = 0.5.
1f. The initial total revenue is $24 a month ´ 204 million
subscribers, which is $4,896 million a month. The new total revenue is $26 a
month ´ 196 million subscribers, which is
$5,096 million a month. So total revenue increases by $5,096 million a month - $4,896 million
a month, which is $200 million a month.
1g. The price elasticity of demand is useful
because it allows us to make precise predictions about how much demanders
change the quantity they demand when the price changes. For instance, if the
price elasticity of demand for AOL is 0.5, then AOL can determine that a 10
percent increase in the price of their service will decrease the quantity that
people demand by 5 percent.
1h. The demand for Internet service is unit
elastic at a price higher than $25 a month. At $25 a month, the elasticity
equals 0.5. As we move up along a linear demand curve, the price elasticity of
demand increases. So the demand for Internet service is unit elastic at the
midpoint of the demand curve, which is at a price greater than $25 a month.
CHECKPOINT
5.2 Price Elasticity of Supply
1a. The supply of asparagus is elastic. The
percentage change in the quantity supplied is greater than the percentage
change in the price.
1b. The supply of asparagus over this large price
range is elastic because there is the possibility of plowing the crop under and
producing nothing. Once harvested, asparagus is not very storable, which makes
supply more inelastic.
1c. The percentage change in the quantity supplied
of asparagus is
which is 200 percent.
The percentage change in the price of asparagus is
which is 100 percent.
So the price elasticity of supply = (200 percent) ÷ (100 percent) = 2.0.


1d. As time passes, the elasticity of supply
increases. After all the technologically possible ways of adjusting production
have been exploited, the supply of asparagus becomes extremely elastic.
2. The percentage change in the price of roses
is ($40) ÷ ($60) ´ 100 = 66.7 percent. The
percentage change in the quantity of roses supplied is (18 million bunches) ÷
(15 million bunches) ´ 100 = 120 percent. So the price
elasticity of supply equals (120 percent) ÷ (66.7 percent), which is 1.80.
CHECKPOINT
5.3 Cross Elasticity and Income
Elasticity
1a. Cola and pizza are complements because they are goods that are consumed
together. More rigorously, the cross elasticity of demand for the two is
negative (when the price of a pizza falls, the quantity of cola demanded increases)
which means the two are complement.
1b. The cross elasticity of demand for cola with respect to pizza
equals the percentage change in the quantity of cola divided by the percentage
change in the price of a pizza. The percentage change in the quantity of cola
equals
which is 50 percent.
The percentage change in the price of a pizza is
which is -25 percent. So
the cross elasticity of demand for cola with respect to pizza is (50 percent)
÷(-25 percent), which is -2.00.


1c. Pizza and burgers are substitutes. A burger can be consumed in
place of a pizza. More rigorously, the cross elasticity of demand for the two
is positive (when in the price of pizza falls, the quantity of burgers demanded
decreases) which means the two are substitutes.
1d. The cross elasticity of demand for burgers with respect to pizza
equals the percentage change in the quantity of burgers divided by the percentage
change in the price of a pizza. Part (a) shows that the percentage change in
the price of pizza is -25 percent. The percentage
change in the quantity of burgers is
which is -66.67 percent.
So the cross elasticity of demand for burgers with respect to pizza is (–66.67
percent) ÷ (-25 percent), which is 2.67.

1e. The owner can determine how the quantities of
burgers and cola he or she sells will change if the price of a nearby pizza
place changes the price of its pizza.
2a. Frozen fish cakes are an inferior good because as income in Miami increases, the
quantity demanded decreases. The income elasticity is negative and the negative
elasticity indicates that frozen fish cakes are an inferior good.
2b. The income elasticity of demand for frozen fish cakes is (-5 percent)
÷ (10 percent) = -0.50.
2c. The income elasticity of demand for fresh fish is (15 percent) ÷(10
percent) = 1.50.
2d. The owner of a fresh fish shop can use these
two elasticities to predict how sales of fresh and frozen fish change when
people’s income change. For instance, if the economy in Miami goes into a recession so that people’s
incomes generally fall, the owner can predict that the quantity of frozen fish
demanded will increase and the quantity of fresh fish demanded will decrease.
As a result, the owner can stock more frozen fish and less fresh fish.

1a. The price elasticity of demand is (2 percent) ¸ (20 percent),
which is 0.10. (Recall that when calculating the price elasticity of demand, we
use absolute values or magnitudes and ignore the minus sign.) So, the demand
for home heating oil is inelastic because the percentage change in quantity demanded
is less than the percentage change in price
1b. Because the demand for home heating oil is inelastic, it is likely
to be a necessity.
1c. Total revenue increases as the price of home heating oil increases.
When the demand for a good is inelastic, price and total revenue change in the
same direction.
1d. The cross elasticity of demand for wool
sweaters with respect to home heating oil is

1e. Home heating oil and sweaters are substitutes
because as the price of home heating oil rises, you can stay warm by using less
home heating oil and putting on a sweater. The cross elasticity of demand for a
substitute is positive.
2a. The percentage change in the quantity of movie tickets demanded
equals
which is 100 percent.
The percentage change in the price of a movie ticket equals
which is 25 percent.
So the demand for movie tickets is elastic because the percentage change in the
quantity demanded is larger than the percentage change in price.


2b. Because the demand is elastic, the fall in the
price of a movie ticket increases the total revenue from the sale of movie
tickets. When the price is $9 a ticket, the total revenue is $9 a ticket ´ 100 tickets,
which is $900. When the price is $7 a ticket, the total revenue is $7 a ticket ´ 300 tickets,
which is $2,100. So the total revenue increases by $1,200.
2c. The price elasticity of demand for movie
tickets is the percentage change in the quantity of movie tickets demanded
divided by the percentage change in the price of a movie ticket. The percentage
change in the quantity of movie tickets demanded equals
which is 100 percent.
The percentage change in the price of a movie ticket equals
which is 25 percent.
So the price elasticity of demand for movie tickets is 100 percent ¸ 25 percent,
which is 4.00.


3. Because the price elasticity of demand for
cookies is 1.5, Pete should lower the price of cookies to raise his total
revenue. Because demand is elastic a decrease in the price of cookies will
bring about a larger percentage increase in the quantity demanded than the
percentage fall in price.
4a. Because the total revenue did not change, the percentage change in
bananas demanded equals the percentage increase in price. Using the midpoint
method, the percentage increase in the price equals ($1.00 ¸ $1.50) = 66.67
percent. So the quantity of bananas demanded decreased by 66.67 percent.
4b. The demand for bananas is unit elastic because
the percentage increase in the price equals the percentage decrease in the
quantity of bananas demanded.
5a. The percentage change in the quantity demanded of plane rides
equals the price elasticity of demand for plane rides multiplied by the percentage
change in the price of a plane ride, which is (0.5) ´ (10 percent) =
5 percent.
5b. The percentage change in the quantity demanded of train rides
equals the cross elasticity of demand for train rides with respect to the price
of a plane ride multiplied by the percentage change in the price of a plane
ride, which is (0.4) ´ (10 percent) = 4 percent.
5c. The percentage change in the quantity demanded of train rides
equals the price elasticity of demand for train rides multiplied by the
percentage change in the price of a train ride, which is (0.2) ´ (10 percent) =
2 percent.
5d. From the answer to part (b), when the price of a plane ride rises
10 percent, the quantity of train rides demanded increases 4 percent. The price
rise of a train ride necessary to decrease the quantity demanded by 4 percent
is 20 percent because a 20 percent increase in the price of train ride
decreases the quantity demanded by (0.2) ´ (20 percent) =
4 percent.
5e. In part (d), the change in the price of a
plane ride leads to a movement along the demand curve for plane rides and a
shift in the demand curve for train rides.
6a. The demand for club memberships increases with income, so club
membership is a normal good. Because the percentage change in the quantity of
club memberships demanded increased by more than the percentage change in
income, the demand for club memberships is income elastic.
6b. The demand for spring water increases with income, so it is a
normal good. Because the percentage change in the quantity of spring water
demanded increased by less than the percentage change in income, the demand for
spring water is income inelastic.
6c. The demand for soft drinks decreases with income, so it is an
inferior good.
6d. The demand for club memberships is income elastic and equals 15 percent
¸ 10 percent, which is 1.5. The demand
for spring water is income inelastic and equals 5 percent ¸ 10 percent,
which is 0.5.
6e. Club memberships and spring water are normal
goods. Soft drinks are an inferior good.
7a. The price elasticity of demand for bus rides is inelastic because
the price elasticity of demand is less than 1.0. When the elasticity is less
than 1.0, an increase in the price of a bus fare brings about a percentage
decrease in the quantity of bus rides demanded that is smaller than the percentage
increase in price.
7b. An increase in the price of bus fares increases the bus company’s
total revenue. Because the demand is inelastic, an increase in the price of the
fare leads to a smaller percentage decrease in the quantity of bus rides demanded
than the percentage increase in the fare. As a result, total revenue increases.
7c. Bus rides and gasoline are substitutes. As the price of gasoline
increases, it becomes more expensive to drive your car and you might decide to
take a bus to work. The cross elasticity of demand between bus rides and
gasoline is positive, indicating that the two are substitutes.
7d. The cross elasticity of demand for bus rides with respect to
gasoline is 0.2, so bus rides increase by (10 percent) ´ (0.2), which
is 2 percent.
7e. The income elasticity of demand is -0.1, so bus
rides decrease by (-0.1) ´ (5 percent),
which is -0.5 percent.
7f. In Pioneer Ville, a bus ride is an inferior good because the income
elasticity of demand is negative. As income increases, fewer bus rides are demanded.
7g. In Pioneer Ville, bus rides and gasoline are
substitutes because the cross elasticity of demand is positive. As the price of
gas increases, the quantity of bus rides demanded increases.
8. Your expenditure on haircuts and food will
more than double because the income elasticity of demand for both exceeds 1.0.
Only if the income elasticity of demand equals 1.0 will the expenditure on a
good or service change proportionally with income.
9a. Rearranging the price elasticity of demand formula shows that the
percentage change in the price of wheat equals the percentage change in the quantity
demanded divided by the price elasticity of demand. So the percentage change in
the price of wheat is (2 percent) ¸ (0.5), which
is 4 percent.
9b. The estimated price elasticity of demand for pasta is equal to the
percentage change in the quantity demanded of pasta divided by the estimated
change in the price of pasta. So the estimated price elasticity of demand for
pasta is (8 percent) ¸ (25 percent), which is 0.32.
9c. The estimated cross elasticity of demand for
pasta sauce with respect to the price of pasta is equal to the percentage
change in the quantity demanded of pasta sauce divided by the estimated change
in the price of pasta. So the estimated cross elasticity of demand for pasta
sauce with respect to the price of pasta is -(5 percent) ¸ (25 percent),
which is -0.2.
10. Probably most students would
continue to buy about the same number of textbooks if the price of textbooks
rose. So, the total expenditure on textbooks would increase. In this case, the
student’s demand for textbooks is inelastic.
chapter SIX
elasticity,
consumer surplus, and Producer Surplus
CHAPTER OVERVIEW
This chapter is
the first of the chapters in Part Two, “Microeconomics of Product
Markets.” Students will benefit by
reviewing Chapter 3’s demand and supply analysis prior to reading this chapter.
Both the
elasticity coefficient and the total revenue test for measuring price
elasticity of demand are presented in the chapter The chapter reviews a number
of applications and presents empirical estimates for a variety of products. Cross- and income elasticities of demand and
price elasticity of supply are also addressed. Finally, this chapter introduces
consumer and producer surplus, as well as efficiency (deadweight) loss.
INSTRUCTIONAL OBJECTIVES
After
completing this chapter, students should be able to:
1. Define demand
and supply and state the laws of demand and supply (review from Chapter 3).
2. Determine
equilibrium price and quantity from supply and demand graphs and schedules
(from Chapter 3).
3. Define price
elasticity of demand and compute the coefficient of elasticity given
appropriate data on prices and quantities.
4. Explain the
meaning of elastic, inelastic, and unitary price elasticity of demand.
5. Recognize
graphs of perfectly elastic and perfectly inelastic demand.
6. Use the total‑revenue
test to determine whether elasticity of demand is elastic, inelastic, or
unitary.
7. List four major
determinants of price elasticity of demand.
8. Explain how a
change in each of the determinants of price elasticity would affect the
elasticity coefficient.
9. Define price elasticity of supply and explain
how the producer’s ability to shift resources to alternative uses and time
affect price elasticity of supply.
10. Explain cross
elasticity of demand and how it is used to determine substitute or
complementary products.
11. Define income
elasticity and its relationship to normal and inferior goods.
12. Define,
measure, and graphically identify consumer surplus.
13. Define,
measure, and graphically identify producer surplus.
14. Identify and
explain efficiency (or deadweight) losses using consumer and producer surplus.
15. Define and
identify the terms and concepts listed at end of the chapter.
LECTURE NOTES
I. Introduction
A. Learning
objectives – In this chapter students will learn:
1. About
price elasticity of demand and how it can be applied.
2. The
usefulness of the total revenue test for price elasticity of demand.
3. About
price elasticity of supply and how it can be applied.
4. About
cross elasticity of demand and income elasticity of demand.
5. About
consumer surplus, producer surplus, and efficiency (deadweight) loss.
B. Elasticity
of demand measures how much the quantity demanded changes with a given change
in price of the item, change in consumers’ income, or change in price of
related product.
C. Price elasticity is a concept that also relates
to supply.
D. The chapter explores both elasticity of
supply and demand and applications of the concept.
II. Price
Elasticity of Demand
A. Law of demand tells us that consumers will
respond to a price decrease by buying more of a product (other things remaining
constant), but it does not tell us how much more.
B. The degree of responsiveness or sensitivity of consumers to a
change in price is measured by the concept of price elasticity of demand.
1. If consumers are relatively responsive to
price changes, demand is said to be elastic.
2. If consumers are relatively unresponsive to
price changes, demand is said to be inelastic.
3. Note that with both elastic and inelastic
demand, consumers behave according to the law of demand; that is, they are
responsive to price changes. The terms elastic or inelastic describe the degree
of responsiveness. A precise definition
of what we mean by “responsive” or “unresponsive” follows.
4. CONSIDER THIS … A Bit of a Stretch
The Ace bandage stretches a lot when force
is applied (elastic); the rubber tie-down (not to be confused with a rubber
band) moves stretches little when force is applied (inelastic).
C. Price elasticity coefficient and formula:
Quantitative measure of elasticity, Ed = percentage change in
quantity/ percentage change in price.
1. Using two price-quantity combinations of a
demand schedule, calculate the percentage change in quantity by dividing the
absolute change in quantity by one of the two original quantities. Then
calculate the percentage change in price by dividing the absolute change in
price by one of the two original prices.
2. Estimate the elasticity of this region of the
demand schedule by comparing the percentage change in quantity and the
percentage change in price. Do not use
the ratio formula at this time.
Emphasize that it is the two percentage changes that are being compared
when determining elasticity.
3. Show that if the other original quantity and
price were used as the denominator that the percentage changes would be
different. Explain that a way to deal
with this problem is to use the average of the two quantities and the average
of the two prices.
4. Using averages – the midpoint formula
a. Using traditional calculations, the measured
elasticity over a given range of prices is sensitive to whether one starts at
the higher price and goes down, or the lower price and goes up. The midpoint formula calculates the average
elasticity over a range of prices to alleviate that problem.
b. The
midpoint formula for elasticity is:
Ed = [(change in Q)/(sum of Q’s/2)] divided by
[(change in P)/(sum of P’s/2)]
c. Have the students calculate each of the
percentage changes separately to determine whether the demand is elastic or
inelastic. After the students have
determined the type of elasticity, then have them insert the percentage changes
into the formula.
d. Students
should practice the exercise in Table 6.1. (Key Question 2)
5. Emphasis: The percentages changes are
compared, not the absolute changes.
a. Absolute changes depend on choice of
units. For example, a change in the
price of a $10,000 car by $1 and is very different than a change in the price a
of $1 can of beer by $1. The auto’s
price is rising by a fraction of a percent while the beer rice is rising 100
percent.
b. Percentages also make it possible to compare
elasticities of demand for different products.
6. Because of the inverse relationship between price and
quantity demanded, the actual elasticity of demand will be a negative
number. However, we ignore the minus
sign and use absolute value of both percentage changes.
7. If the coefficient of elasticity of demand is a number
greater than one, we say demand is elastic; if the coefficient is less than
one, we say demand is inelastic. In other words, the quantity demanded is
“relatively responsive” when Ed is greater than 1 and “relatively unresponsive”
when Ed is less than 1. A special case
is if the coefficient equals one; this is called unit elasticity.
8. Note: Inelastic demand does not mean that
consumers are completely unresponsive.
This extreme situation called perfectly inelastic demand would be very
rare, and the demand curve would be vertical.
9. Likewise, elastic demand does not mean
consumers are completely responsive to a price change. This extreme situation, in which a small
price reduction would cause buyers to increase their purchases from zero to all
that it is possible to obtain, is perfectly elastic demand, and the demand
curve would be horizontal.
D. Graphical analysis:
1. Illustrate graphically perfectly elastic,
relatively elastic, unitary elastic, relative inelastic, and perfectly
inelastic. (Figures 6.1 and 6.2)
2. Using Figure 6.2, explain that elasticity
varies over range of prices.
a. Demand is more elastic in upper left portion
of curve (because price is higher, quantity smaller).
b. Demand is more inelastic in lower right
portion of curve (because price is lower, quantity larger).
3. It is impossible to judge elasticity of a
single demand curve by its flatness or steepness, since demand elasticity can
measure both elastic and inelastic at different points on the same demand
curve.
E. Total-revenue test is the easiest way to judge whether demand
is elastic or inelastic. This
test can be used in place of elasticity formula, unless there is a need to
determine the elasticity coefficient.
1. Elastic
demand and the total-revenue test: Demand is elastic if a decrease in price
results in a rise in total revenue, or if an increase in price results in a
decline in total revenue. (Price and revenue
move in opposite directions).
2. Inelastic demand and the total-revenue test:
Demand is inelastic if a decrease in price results in a fall in total revenue,
or an increase in price results in a rise in total revenue. (Price and revenue move in same direction).
3. Unit elasticity and the total-revenue test:
Demand has unit elasticity if total revenue does not change when the price
changes.
4. The graphical representation of the
relationship between total revenue and price elasticity is shown in Figure 6.2.
5. Table 6.2 provides a summary of the rules and
concepts related to elasticity of demand.
F. There are several determinants of the price elasticity of
demand.
1. Substitutes for the product: Generally, the more
substitutes, the more elastic the demand.
2. The proportion of price relative to income:
Generally, the larger the expenditure relative to one’s budget, the more
elastic the demand, because buyers notice the change in price more.
3. Whether the product is a luxury or a necessity:
Generally, the less necessary the item, the more elastic the demand.
4. The amount of time involved: Generally, the longer
the time period involved, the more elastic the demand becomes.
G. Table 6.3 presents some real‑world price
elasticities. Use the determinants discussed
to see if the actual elasticities are equivalent to what one would
predict.
H. There are many practical applications of the
price elasticity of demand.
1. Inelastic demand for agricultural products
helps to explain why bumper crops depress the prices and total revenues for
farmers.
2. Governments look at elasticity of demand when
levying excise taxes. Excise taxes on
products with inelastic demand will raise the most revenue and have the least
impact on quantity demanded for those products.
3. Demand for cocaine is highly inelastic and
presents problems for law enforcement.
Stricter enforcement reduces supply, raises prices and revenues for
sellers, and provides more incentives for sellers to remain in business. Crime may also increase as buyers have to
find more money to buy their drugs.
a. Opponents of legalization think that
occasional users or “dabblers” have a more elastic demand and would increase
their use at lower, legal prices.
b. Removal of the legal prohibitions might make
drug use more socially acceptable and shift demand to the right.
III. Price
Elasticity of Supply
A. The concept of price elasticity also applies
to supply. The elasticity formula is the
same as that for demand, but we must substitute the word “supplied” for the
word “demanded” everywhere in the formula.
Es = percentage change in
quantity supplied / percentage change in price
As with price elasticity of demand, the
midpoints formula is more accurate.
B. The ease of shifting resources between
alternative uses is very important in price elasticity of supply because it
will determine how much flexibility a producer has to adjust his/her output to
a change in the price. The degree of flexibility, and therefore the time
period, will be different in different industries. (Figure 6.4)
1. The market period is so short that elasticity
of supply is inelastic; it could be almost perfectly inelastic or
vertical. In this situation, it is
virtually impossible for producers to adjust their resources and change the
quantity supplied. (Think of adjustments
on a farm once the crop has been planted.)
2. The short‑run supply elasticity is more
elastic than the market period and will depend on the ability of producers to
respond to price change. Industrial
producers are able to make some output changes by having workers work overtime
or by bringing on an extra shift.
3. The long‑run supply elasticity is the most
elastic, because more adjustments can be made over time and quantity can be
changed more relative to a small change in price, as in Figure 6.4c. The producer has time to build a new plant.
C. Applications of the price elasticity of
supply.
1. Antiques and other non-reproducible
commodities are inelastic in supply, sometimes the supply
is perfectly inelastic. This makes their
prices highly susceptible to fluctuations in demand.
2. Gold prices are volatile because the supply
of gold is highly inelastic, and unstable demand resulting from speculation
causes prices to fluctuate significantly.
IV. Cross
elasticity and income elasticity of demand:
A. Cross elasticity of demand refers to the
effect of a change in a product’s price on the quantity demanded for another
product. Numerically, the formula is
shown for products X and Y.
Exy = (percentage change in
quantity of X) / (percentage change in price of Y)
1. If
cross elasticity is positive, then X and Y are substitutes.
2. If
cross elasticity is negative, then X and Y are complements.
3. Note: if cross elasticity is zero, then X and Y are
unrelated, independent products.
B. Income elasticity of demand refers to the
percentage change in quantity demanded that results from some percentage change
in consumer incomes.
Ei = (percentage change in
quantity demanded) / (percentage change in income)
1. A
positive income elasticity indicates a normal or superior good.
2. A
negative income elasticity indicates an inferior good.
3. Those
industries that are income elastic will expand at a higher rate as the economy
grows.
V. Consumer and Producer Surplus
A. Consumer Surplus
1. Definition
– the difference between the maximum price a consumer is (or consumers are)
willing to pay for a product and the actual price.
2. The
surplus, measurable in dollar terms, reflects the extra utility gained
from paying a lower price than what is
required to obtain the good.
3. Consumer
surplus can be measured by calculating the difference between the maximum willingness to pay and the actual
price for each consumer, and then summing those differences.
4. Consumer
surplus is measured and represented graphically by the area under the demand curve and above the equilibrium
price. (Figure 6.5)
5. Consumer
surplus and price are inversely related – all else equal, a higher price
reduces consumer surplus.
B. Producer Surplus
1. Definition – the
difference between the actual price a producer receives (or producers receive) and the minimum acceptable
price.
2. Producer
surplus can be measured by calculating the difference between the minimum acceptable price and the actual
price for each unit sold, and then summing those differences.
3. Producer
surplus is measured and represented graphically by the area above the supply curve and below the equilibrium
price. (Figure 6.6)
4. Producer
surplus and price are directly related – all else equal, a higher price
increases producer surplus.
VI. Efficiency
Revisited and Efficiency Losses
A. Efficiency
is attained at equilibrium, where the combined consumer and producer surplus is
maximized. (Figure 6.7)
1. Consumers receive utility up to their maximum
willingness to pay, but only have to pay the equilibrium price.
2. Producers receive the equilibrium price for
each unit, but it only costs the minimum acceptable price to produce.
3. Allocative efficiency occurs at quantity levels
where three conditions exist:
a. MB = MC
b. Maximum willingness to pay = minimum
acceptable price.
c. Combined consumer and producer surplus is at
a maximum.
B. Efficiency (Deadweight) Losses
1. Underproduction
reduces both consumer and producer surplus, and efficiency is lost because both buyers and sellers would be
willing to exchange a higher quantity.
2. Overproduction causes inefficiency because
past the equilibrium quantity, it costs society more to produce the good than it is worth to the consumer in
terms of willingness to pay.
.
Price Elasticity of
Supply
Definition of price elasticity of supply
Price
elasticity of supply measures the relationship between change in quantity supplied and a
change in price.
If supply is elastic, producers can increase output without a rise in
cost or a time delay
If supply is inelastic, firms find it hard to change production in a given time period.
If supply is inelastic, firms find it hard to change production in a given time period.
The formula for price elasticity of supply is:
% change in quantity
supplied
% change in price
- When Pes > 1, then supply is price elastic
- When Pes < 1, then supply is price inelastic
- When Pes = 0, supply is perfectly inelastic
- When Pes = infinity, supply is perfectly elastic following a change in demand
Factors that Affect
Price Elasticity of Supply
(1) Spare production capacity
If there is plenty of spare
capacity then a business should be able to increase its output
without a rise in costs and therefore supply will be elastic in response to a
change in demand. The supply of goods and services is often most elastic in a
recession, when there is plenty of spare labour and capital resources available
to step up output as the economy recovers.
(2) Stocks of finished products and components
If stocks of raw materials and finished products
are at a high level then a firm is able to respond to a change in demand
quickly by supplying these stocks onto the market - supply will be elastic.
Conversely when stocks are low, dwindling supplies force prices higher and
unless stocks can be replenished, supply will be inelastic in response to a
change in demand.
(3) The ease and cost of factor substitution
If both capital and labour resources are occupationally
mobile then the elasticity of supply for a product is higher
than if capital and labour cannot easily and quickly be switched
(4) Time period involved in the production process
Supply is more price elastic the longer the time
period that a firm is allowed to adjust its production levels.
In some agricultural markets for example, the momentary supply
is fixed and is determined mainly by planting decisions made months before, and
also climatic conditions, which affect the overall production yield.
![]()
An empty
restaurant – plenty of spare capacity to meet any rise in demand!
|
![]()
When
telecommunications networks get congested at peak times, the elasticity of
supply to meet rising demand may be low
|
![]()
Stocks
in a warehouse – businesses with plentiful stocks can supply quickly and
easily onto the market when demand changes
|
![]()
For many
agricultural products there are time lags in the production process which
means that elasticity of supply is very low in the immediate or momentary
time period
|
Supply curves with
different price elasticity of supply

The non-linear supply
curve
A non linear supply curve has a changing price
elasticity of supply throughout its length. This is illustrated in the diagram
below.

Useful applications of price elasticity of demand and supply
Elasticity of demand and supply is tested in
virtually every area of the AS economics syllabus. The key is to understand the
various factors that determine the responsiveness of consumers and producers to
changes in price. The elasticity will affect the ways in which price and output
will change in a market. And elasticity is also significant in determining some
of the effects of changes in government policy when the state chooses to
intervene in the price mechanism.
Some relevant issues that directly use elasticity of demand and supply
include:
- Taxation: The effects of indirect taxes and subsidies on the level of demand and output in a market e.g. the effectiveness of the congestion charge in reducing road congestion; or the impact of higher duties on cigarettes on the demand for tobacco and associated externality effects
- Changes in the exchange rate: The impact of changes in the exchange rate on the demand for exports and imports
- Exploiting monopoly power in a market: The extent to which a firm or firms with monopoly power can raise prices in markets to extract consumer surplus and turn it into extra profit (producer surplus)
- Government intervention in the market: The effects of the government introducing a minimum price (price floor) or maximum price (price ceiling) into a market
Elasticity of demand and supply also affects the
operation of the price mechanism as a means of rationing scarce goods
and services among competing uses and in determining how
producers respond to the incentive of a higher market price.
![]() |
Chapter
|
4
|
ELASTICITY
|
Outline
I. Price Elasticity of Demand
A. Figure
4.1 shows how the demand curve influences the price and quantity
responses that result from a given change in supply. The figure highlights the
need for a measure of the responsiveness of the quantity demanded to a price
change.
B. The price
elasticity of demand is a units-free measure of the responsiveness of the
quantity demanded of a good to a change in its price when all other influences
on buyers’ plans remain the same.
C. Calculating
Elasticity
1. The price elasticity of demand is equal to
.

2. To calculate the price elasticity of demand,
we express the change in price as a percentage of the average price—the midpoint between the initial and new price.
3. Similarly
we
express the change in the quantity demanded as a percentage of the average quantity demanded—the average of
the initial and new quantity.

a) By using the average price and average
quantity, the elasticity is the same value whether the price rises or
falls.
b) The ratio of two proportionate changes is the same as the ratio of two percentage changes. The measure is
“units-free” because it is a ratio of two percentage changes and the
percentages cancel out. Changing the units of measurement of price or quantity
leave the value of the elasticity the same.
c) The demand elasticity formula yields a
negative value, because price and quantity move in opposite directions.
However, it is the magnitude, or
absolute value, of the measure that reveals how responsive the quantity change
has been to a price change. So we use the magnitude or the absolute value of
the price elasticity of demand.
D. Inelastic and Elastic Demand
Demand can be inelastic, unit elastic, or
elastic, and can range from zero to infinity.
1. If the quantity demanded doesn’t change when
the price changes, the price elasticity of demand is zero and demand is perfectly inelastic. The demand curve
is vertical. Figure 4.3a illustrates this case.
2. If the percentage change in the quantity
demanded equals the percentage change in price, the value of the price
elasticity of demand equals 1 and demand is unit elastic. Figure 4.3b illustrates this case—a demand curve
with ever declining slope. (Note that
a unit elastic demand curve is not linear.)
3. Between the two previous cases, the
percentage change in the quantity demanded is smaller than the percentage
change in price so that the value of the price elasticity of demand is less
than 1 and demand is inelastic.
4. If the percentage change in the quantity
demanded is infinitely large when the price barely changes, the value of the
price elasticity of demand is infinite and demand is perfectly elastic. The demand curve is horizontal. Figure 4.3c illustrates this case.
5. If the percentage change in the quantity
demanded is greater than the percentage change in price, the value of the price
elasticity of demand is greater than 1 and
demand is elastic.


1. While moving along a linear demand curve, the
demand becomes less elastic as the price falls. Figure 4.4 illustrates this
fact.
2. Demand is unit elastic at the mid-point of
the demand curve.
E. Total
Revenue and Elasticity
1. The total
revenue from the sale of good equals the price of the good multiplied by
the quantity sold.
2. The change in total revenue from a change in
price depends upon the elasticity of demand:
a) If demand is elastic, a 1 percent price cut
increases the quantity sold by more than 1 percent, and total revenue
increases.
b) If demand is inelastic, a 1 percent price
cut decreases the quantity sold by more than 1 percent, and total revenue
decreases.
c) If demand is unitary elastic, a 1 percent
price cut increases the quantity sold by 1 percent, and total revenue remains
unchanged.

a) If a price cut increases total revenue, then
demand is elastic.
b) If a price cut decreases total revenue, then
demand is inelastic.
c) If a price cut leaves total revenue
unchanged, then demand is unitary elastic.
4. Figure 4.5 shows the relationship between elasticity of demand for pizzas and
the total revenues from pizza sales across the entire demand curve for pizza.
F. The
Factors That Influence the Elasticity of Demand
The magnitude of the elasticity of demand
depends on three factors:
1. The closeness
of substitutes:
a) The closer the substitutes for a good or
service, the more elastic the demand for it.
b) Necessities, such as food or housing,
generally have inelastic demand.
c) Luxuries, such as exotic vacations,
generally have elastic demand.
2. The
proportion of income spent on the good.
a) The greater the proportion of income
consumers spend on a good, the larger is the demand elasticity for that good.

3. The
time elapsed since a price change.
a) The more time consumers have to adjust to a
price change the more elastic the demand for that good.
II. More Elasticities of Demand
A. Cross
Elasticity of Demand
1. The cross
elasticity of demand is a measure of the responsiveness of demand for a
good to a change in the price of a substitute
or a compliment, other things remaining the same.
2. The formula for the cross elasticity of
demand is:


b) The cross elasticity of demand for a complement is negative. Figure
4.7 shows the decrease in the
quantity of pizza demanded when the price of a soft drink (a complement of
pizza) rises.
B. Income
Elasticity of Demand
1. The income
elasticity of demand measures the responsiveness of the demand for a good
or service to a change in income, other things remaining the same.
2. The formula for the income elasticity of
demand is:

a) If the income elasticity of demand is
greater than 1, demand is income elastic
and the good is a normal good.
b) If the income elasticity of demand is
positive but less than 1, demand is income
inelastic and the good is a normal
good.

3. Table 4.2 shows estimates of income elasticity of demand for various goods
and services.


A. Figure 4.9 shows how the supply curve influences the price and quantity
responses that result from a given change in demand and highlights the need for
a measure of the responsiveness of the quantity supplied to a price change.
B. The
elasticity of supply measures the
responsiveness of the quantity supplied to a change in the price of a good when
all other influences on selling plans remain the same.
C. Calculating
the Elasticity of Supply
1. The formula for the elasticity of supply is:

2. Figure 4.10 shows three cases of the elasticity of supply.

a) Supply is perfectly inelastic if the elasticity of supply equals 0. In this
case, as Figure 4.10a
shows, the supply curve is vertical.
b) Supply is unit elastic if the elasticity of supply equals 1. In this case, as
Figure 4.10b shows, the supply curve is linear and passes through the origin.
The slope of the supply curve is irrelevant.
c) Supply is perfectly elastic if the elasticity of supply is infinite. In this
case, as Figure 4.10c
shows, the supply curve is horizontal.
D. The
Factors That Influence the Elasticity of Supply
The elasticity of supply depends on
1. Resource
substitution possibilities: The easier it is to substitute among the
resources used to produce a good or service, the greater is its elasticity of
supply.
2. The
time frame for supply decisions: The more time that passes after a price
change, the greater is the elasticity of supply.
E. Table 4.3 provides a glossary of the all
elasticity measures.

No comments:
Post a Comment